Several concepts of modern capitalism have emerged
from the ranks of German Social-Democracy. One of them
represented the “justification of modern relations and the subordination of
working-class policy to the interests of imperialism. From the recognition of
the necessity of imperialism, it created the theoretical foundation for a
national-liberal (and sometimes even national-imperialist) policy. It was about
this position that Parvus said at the time when it
was first formulated: “It restricts its criticism to external manifestations
only and preserves the opposition’s stance solely by the grace of the colonial
bandits and various scoundrels who care only about filling out the newspaper
column marked 'colonial horrors'. Another concept also did not doubt the
historical necessity of imperialism. From here it goes on to, however,
theoretically(!!) conclude that
we are experiencing the ultimate development of the capitalist mode of
production, and to the political conclusion that it is time for the working
class to take the path of revolutionary destruction of capitalism. This is the
least formalized of all the social-democratic concepts of modern capitalism, it
is largely located in the sphere of unresolved contradictions, its theoretical
implications have not been systematically worked out and its extremism
sometimes too unceremoniously rejects real relations. In addition, in the hands
of one of its representatives, Rosa Luxemburg, it took on a clearly erroneous
form. However, in the works of its other representatives there are many
elements for the construction of a genuine Marxist theory of imperialism. This
will refer to Parvus, Pannekoek,
Lengau, and Radek. Finally,
the third concept, emerging from the depths of German Social
Democracy, is constructed by the “centre.” It denies imperialism as a
transitional stage from capitalism to socialism. It cohabits with good old
books and refuses to recognize contemporary relationships, if in these books
nothing is written about them. It is afraid of the
decisive actions dictated by the modern economy. It hopes to bring back the
old, original relations of “peaceful”, “free” capitalism: after all, it would
so simply, so serenely lead us to socialism! Its author is Kautsky, who developed it himself and developed it in full
accordance with the evolution of centrism. As for Hilferding,
although he proceeded from the position of the same centrism and received
considerable laurels from right-wing theoreticians his
theory never became the theory of the party. It can be said
that Hilferding’s theory
enjoyed greater prominence among the Russian Marxists than among the Germans1. Kautskyism remained the official concept of imperialism in
the German theatre, an examination of which we consider to be
our aim.
In 1901, in the book “Social Democracy and Trade
Policy,” written in connection with the expiry in 1903 of the terms of the most
important German trade treaties and the appearance on the political forefront
of the question of the further course of imperial trade policy, Kautsky had to for the first time coherently characterized
the characteristics of modern capitalism.
Young business cartels and syndicates, especially in heavy
industry; steep agricultural protectionism; a rapidly growing, in the
capitalist environment, taste for industrial protectionism; a rise in prices,
especially in agriculture; aggressive colonial policies; thwarting the economic
struggle of the working class; use of state power in the service of the ruling
capitalist clique and the general intensification of the political reaction —
these are the patchy features of the new capitalist entity that manifested
itself at about that time. Much here was absolutely for, theoretically
yet not captured, politically incomprehensible. However, the
fact that something looked like the old, long-surpassed stage (protectionism,
colonial politics, etc.) thus promoted analogies with the undeveloped,
imperfect forms of capitalism, as well as that important fact, that the
socio-political manifestations of the new system collided sharply with the
abstract, “habitual” and “self-evident” idea of strengthening democratic and
cultural principles — all this severely impeded the scientific analysis of the
newest capitalist phenomena. The task of a Marxist is:
to give a dialectical systematization of these phenomena, i.e. understand from
where, how and where they grow, each individually and collectively, as a single
system. It is impossible to say that “Kautsky did not see this task and did not try to solve it." But did he succeed in this?
The next place from the book “Social Democracy and
Trade Policy" shows how clearly and comprehensively did the Kautsky of that period understand the new capitalism. The
reader, we hope, will forgive, if we present here almost completely the chapter
under the beautiful name — "The New Policy of Violence.” Violence is the essence
of the cartel economy (German: Cartellenwirtschaft);
cartels are trying to fight violently, to suppress their opponents not yet with
guns and cannons, but with violent measures of economic struggle...
No less violently do the cartel-monopolists (Kartellemonopolisten)
operate in foreign countries. First,
they try to destroy their competitors by driving down the prices. They
can afford a longer decline in prices abroad, as protectionist
duties are so high and the cartels prosper so greatly that the
industrialists
are able to raise the prices much above the normal in the domestic
market and
through the increase in prices of the products in their homeland to
receive
additional profits that reward them for the dirty competition in the
world
market. But since the competitor begins to
imitate these noble methods, they soon become unworkable.
Then they go further and try to
forcibly acquire a market in which they would occupy a preferential
position. Colonial and expansionist policy now appears on the scene. This
policy, in turn, causes conflicts or threatens conflicts between competing
industrial powers, a struggle with violent economic measures threatens to
be transformed into a struggle with gunpowder, lead and dynamite. Further
preparations necessary for the war benefit the cartel economy; the consequence
of all this is an increase of colonial adventures, the increasing dangers of war.
Thus, instead of the spirit of free trade, the spirit
of violence among the industrial bourgeoisie is intensified. Previously
peacefully minded, it dreamt of eternal peace, condemned war as a remnant of
medieval barbarism, which can serve only dynastic and feudal purposes; now it is more and more filled with the spirit of
violence, no matter how bitterly some individual ideologists cry about it.
Protectionism is only a link in this chain of the new
industrial system, which is the newest and probably the last form of
manifestation of the capitalist mode of production. But
he who recognizes this link alone must, if he wants to be consistent,
recognize the other links that are logically connected with it..
Unfortunately, this remarkable place serves Kautsky
only for characterizing the general economic and political tone of the “new
industrial system”. Kautsky conducts a theoretical
analysis on a completely different path without touching the most profound of
the points mentioned, but for the most part contradicts them.
“The
modern mode of production is based on the division of labor
between the industrial and agrarian states and the ever increasing export of
industrial products from the former and agrarian from the latter” (p. 116).
“The necessity of exporting industrial products for their exchange with
agricultural is a consequence of the increasing accumulation of capital" (p. 121).
With these words, Kautsky gave
a better formulation of his theoretical views during the period under
consideration. The sloppiness, colourlessness and underdevelopment of the
formulation reflect quite well the state of the ideas of the author. When
certain questions are explained, these fundamental
ideas are examined, however, with insufficient perseverance.
First, protection: “The new patronizing system is a
system of a modern state, exporting the products of industry and importing life
supplies.
In the modern patronizing system, the main role is played by agricultural duties; they are the centre, the
axis, around which everything revolves, and industrial duties are only a more
or less important appendage. With the old patronage system
it was the other way around" (pp. 54-55)2.
The second, export of
capital. The logical difficulties that arise for Kautsky
are “overcome” in such a way that the export of industrial capital in
monetary
form (capital investment abroad), which is characteristic of the
process, is
replaced in Kautsky’s view by the export of means
of production (commodity exports). Kautsky’s
theoretical construct is extremely simple: old capitalism exported
means of
consumption (textiles), the new one — means of production (machines,
etc.); and
this change should, among other things, be especially evident in the
consolidating system of relations between the industrial and agrarian
countryside... But what about the direct export of capital abroad that
is growing in our
time (financing, etc.)? For Kautsky, this is only a
means for an advanced country to develop its own industry, a dubious
means,
because the industry here “paid for its own growth”3.
But what about the fact that it was precisely (and only) the industrial
development of a backward country that used to, first and foremost, shrink its
import of consumer goods and raise its demand for the means of production? Does
this not show that the phenomenon that Kautsky
presents as the relationship between an industrial and agrarian country (the
export of capital in the form of means of production) is in fact the
relationship between an industrial and an industrialized country?
Third, the desire of the industrial countries to
monopolize the markets of the agrarian countries. Kautsky
in the pamphlet considers two ways in which it is done.
First, the idea of new customs unions (Panamerican, Central European
and of Great Britain). He believes that failure of this idea is unavoidable for
the reason that, unlike the old customs unions of the last century, “modern
plans of customs unions seek to unite those states each of which conducts an
independent political and economic life, that are located on different levels
development. Every single one therefore needs a special policy. All the
trade-and-political contradictions that exist inside the state in the form of
class contradictions act here in the form of state contradictions between the classes
that are fighting amongst themselves" (p. 114). In order not to discredit his
scheme, Kautsky had to change the actual relations.
It is clear to everyone that if the plans of the customs union of the advanced
and backward countries are not feasible, it is not because
the interests of agrarian and industrial countries are inconsistent, but
on the contrary, in the main, because a growing industrial capitalism comes in
the way of harmonizing these interests. But, according
to Kautsky, it should be quite possible to have a
customs union of industrial countries that are economically homogeneous: is
there not, already in 1901, a very slight hint of the future theory of
ultra-imperialism here?
Secondly, “the aspirations of the great industrial
countries to monopolize part of the world market” leads to “the
subjugation of
agrarian countries through policy of expansion and violent
imperialism.” But “the soon the latter will be completely divided, then
only one way will remain to expand the monopolized region: not the
struggle between the industrial and agrarian states, but a bloody
struggle of
the great industrial powers among themselves — a world war.”
And the final conclusion of Kautsky’s
scheme at that time was: “A World War is only one of the alternatives to the
modern, world-wide trading system that is at the brink of death; the second
alternative is a socialist society" (pp. 116-117). To what extent it was a Marxist
speaking about this contradiction, the reader will find out at the end of the
chapter.
We have briefly summarized in his own words the
author’s theoretical understanding of the modern stage of capitalism,
which Kautsky developed in 1901. Within this system of views,
there was no logically legitimate place for a “cartel economy”. The
latter is located by Kautsky
outside the main scheme, or, more accurately, is introduced into it by
Kautsky from the outside; “Cartel economy” thus does not
determine the basic law of modern capitalism, but is not generated by
it
either. But then the “cartel economy” only
strengthens the immanent tendencies of the “new industrial system”; it
itself
grows out of other, for this system, secondary and unrelated sources,
and
therefore cannot be a necessity for it. Indeed, in the resolution on
trade
policy proposed by the Kautsky at the Stuttgart Party Congress of 1898 and
adopted by the Congress, two points
are devoted to the maliciousness of the system of cartels and trusts
for
economic development.
But if cartels can only be said to be harmful to
capitalist development, then what remains of the “new industrial system”? After
all, it then turns out that this “new system” is not at all qualitatively
different from the good old capitalist system; after all, Kautsky
acknowledges that the foreign policy of classical England in its classical
capitalist development represented the desire of an industrial country to
expand into the agrarian regions. The essence of the new industrial system
turns out to be a simple quantitative development of the old. And the best proof that Kautsky did not
go beyond the limits of classical capitalism in his ideas about the modern
economy and that he overlooked the quantification of the modification of the
capitalist system lies in the method he uses when criticizing protectionism and
export of capital, as he criticizes these phenomena from the point of view of
their profitability for capitalist management. Many pages are covered
with arguments and numerical calculations that are designed to prove that
capitalism itself is “not interested” in either protectionism or export of
capital. That “for industrial countries, like Germany, France, the United
States, England, free trade is the least of evils” (p. 60). That the productive
forces that would otherwise remain inside the country are flowing abroad, and the development of foreign industry is supported
at the expense of the industry of their own country” (p. 61). That
protectionism, export of capital, colonial policy are beneficial only to a
group of privileged capitalists, especially owners of heavy industry, and the
entire capitalist world is groaning under their burden.4
For Kautsky in 1901, modern
capitalism is decaying capitalism — capitalism that develops its negative
properties to the extreme, extremely intensifying the exploitation of the
working class and oppressing the consumer. The task of Social-Democracy
is to cut off these harmful growths on the capitalist organism and thereby also
ensure the normal and rapid development of the productive forces, albeit, with
some damage to certain groups of capitalists. Is such a policy real? Of course,
Kautsky asks no such question. The whole book about
trade policy is written without asking such a
question. This utopianism is rooted in the inevitable contradictory nature of
the working-class policy, since it (the policy) does not, in the era of
imperialism, have the aim of preparing for a “socialist revolution” as its
basis and its core. Of course, one cannot blame Kautsky
of 1901 for preaching an unrealistic trade policy5. Its unrealistic
nature came from the undeveloped relations that characterise the transition
from developed capitalism to decaying capitalism. A “good” real policy was at
the time meant only for those leaders of the working class who were orienting
themselves in conditions of the decline of the class struggle, towards the
consolidation of “national interests,” that is, imperialist leaders of the
workers’ movement. Already in 1898
Max Schippel conducted a “real” policy, not out of fear, but a matter of conscience.
We see that in 1901 Kautsky,
who observed the birth of the “new industrial system,” failed to
theoretically
capture the wealth of the new phenomena and new forms and come to an
understanding of these as a system. His analysis is one-sided. He saw
only the
contradictions of the new system, but did not notice that these are
contradictions of progressive factors and of a progressive process.
Meanwhile, it is only this contradictory progressive nature that
allows us to talk about the “industrial system” of modern capitalism.
In
the “cartel” Kautsky saw only “a policy of violence", but did not want to understand that the rise of cartels and trusts
are a
spontaneously growing trend towards planned economy, which is inevitably
irrational under capitalism, and therefore violent and painful. In
protectionism
and export of capital, Kautsky saw only the
“constraining of the productive forces and the expansion of capitalist
exploitation," but did not notice that the export of capital and
protectionism
is a natural, inevitable, but inevitably antagonistic and violent
method, with
the help of which contemporary capitalism is developing the world
economy.
We are living in a period of “a new, perhaps, final
form of manifestation of the capitalist mode of production,” Kautsky writes in 1901 (p. 51). But
why is this the final form? After all, if it is possible to overcome the
harmful properties of modern capitalism, then it will continue to develop well.
The reformist answers this question: modern capitalism is capitalism,
that is in an organized, and, consequently, peaceful manner growing into
a socialist system. But wherefrom does Kautsky, a revolutionary who even refuses to accept the
organizational forms of modern capitalism, draw his conclusion about the final form of manifestation of the capitalist
mode of production? It is from here: “We are approaching the moment when the
division of labour between the industrial and agrarian state is narrowing more
and more, thanks to the fact that the former are increasingly outweighed by the
latter. Once such a number of agrarian states are turned into industrial ones,
when the ones that remain are insufficient to absorb all the products of the
industrial states and are not able to supply them with the necessary quantity
of food supplies and raw material, then this division of labor
has reached its ultimate goal. We should not, however, think that here we are
talking about a very distant future“ (my italics,
E.L.) ... Moreover, one cannot expect that commodity trade, stemming from the
position of universal debt, will long survive the division of labour between
industrial and agrarian states".
“But
these destroy the very foundation that has thus far made possible the rapid
development of industrial exports that has become a necessary condition for the
existence of developed capitalist industrialised countries. What then remains?
Then surely there will come a moment when the current
trading system will collapse just as Manchester collapsed in the second half of
the 1970s."
This reasoning sheds light on the historical stages of
the theories of imperialism and helps to understand the theoretical evolution
of not just Kautsky. There is no doubt that, in
particular, R. Luxembourg built her own landmark under the impression of Kautsky’s views-the dominant views in German social
democracy. As for Kautsky himself, I must say that he
logically derived his theory of the collapse of capitalism from his basic
thesis, which characterizes the modern mode of production as based on the
division of labour between the agrarian and industrial countries.
So, the moment is near when “the current trading system
will collapse just as Manchester system collapsed in the second half of the
1870s”. So what is next? How does Kautsky conceive of
further development? The answer is found in his
articles on the Anglo-Boer War.
The main idea of the articles:
“The
times of liberalism have passed, we will never return to them” (327).
The banner of freedom and antimilitarism, which was lost by the
bourgeoisie, must be raised by the proletariat. Two ruins of
Manchesterism are fighting for domination over the minds of
the English proletariat, two ideas — socialism and imperialism.
Ultimately, the Manchester views will only be replaced by the socialist views, which,
in
foreign policy, and precisely in colonial politics, do not differ much
from
Manchester views” (308). “If the policies of Rhodes and Chamberlain
fail, then
it will serve as a powerful impetus toward socialism and at the same
time
increase hopes for development in a democratic, and consequently, in a
relatively peaceful way.” “The more this is clarified, the sooner the
broad
masses of the British proletariat will lean toward further development
of the
present capitalist system in the sense of socialism, instead of
striving for
imperialism” (p. 112) (“The Common Problems of International Socialism,”
St.
Petersburg, 1906).
So that’s the sort of socialism Kautsky
had in mind when he formulated the two alternatives of the developments in the
near future! Socialism, that he gave a call for, already in that spotless dawn
of centrism was “democratic” and a “further development of the present
capitalist system in the sense of socialism”.
II.
Daring Youth (1905-1909).
In
the period that we are now going to study Kautsky’s
views on modern capitalism were expounded chiefly in connection with the
colonial problem, namely in connection with the polemics about the relationship
of social democracy to contemporary colonial politics, which took place,
approximately, in 1905-1909 in the international socialist spheres. First of all we are referring to Kautsky’s
book Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik [Socialism and Colonial Politics],
Berlin, 1907, written during the Stuttgart Congress of
the Second International.
That was the time when the basic relations of the
imperialist era had sufficiently crystallized. Incessant
international conflicts centred around the colonies, some of which led to wars
(the 1900 Boxer war, England vs. Tibet, Germany vs. Guerrero, Russo-Japanese
war), and each of the rest represented a war of five minutes; the frantic
growth of armaments and the wave of “patriotism” rising among the inhabitants
of all countries, that is, chauvinism; the onset of a reaction supported and
pushed by finance capital. The main divisions have also already
occurred in the labour movement. Opportunism got
consolidated, even reinforced by a faction of the social-imperialists
(especially Leitner). And looking
back at that epoch from a distance of two decades full of great tests such as
war and the post-war struggle of the working class, we see that the “centre” by
that time had fully formed and been politically determined. Then the 4th
of August, which seemed to the contemporaries to be a steep turn and a betrayal
of the past days, we are forced to regard as a perfectly natural development
of the tendencies that had taken hold of the “centre” already in the period
under consideration. Take, for example, the colonial question, close to
our topic. Bernstein in Stuttgart justifies his old programme of socialist
colonial policy. “A large part of our economy is built on products from the
colonies, with which the natives do not know what to do.” David in Stuttgart,
however, mocks Ledeburg, who defends the liberation
of the colonies: “Humanity would prevail then in the colonies, on the contrary,
they would again fall into barbarism,” and the Dutchman Van Kol,
reporter, proclaims: “With weapons in hand we go to
the colony “... Kautsky is fighting against socialist
colonial policy with the directness and perseverance of a genuine Marxist-
revolutionary. But Kautsky
is only a theorist of the “centre”. Well, as for the actual leaders of the
centre (to which Kautsky, in fact, never belonged),
how did they behave in this dispute of the greatest importance? Bebel in 1906
in the Reichstag developed the idea of civilizational colonial policy. Paul
Zinger at the Essen Party Congress in 1907, reporting on
behalf of the party about the Stuttgart International Stitch essay, ridiculed
the whole of the dispute. He said: “It was, in fact,
more a dispute about words, than a deep fundamental difference”. And then he adds “In general, I believe that for us, Social
Democrats, it is a mistake and fraught with distorted notions, if we were to
equip ourselves with this word (colonial policy). What we can
demand in our present society, and what we must demand (since we are talking
about the Reichstag faction) also in the contemporary colonial policy is – on
the contrary — a civilizing policy this is opposite to the civilizing policy".6
It is characteristic that at the
same time, Jaures preached “peaceful intrusion” in Morocco, and
Vanderveld in a remarkable article on the colonial position
(“NZ”, 1907-1, p. 829), with admirable dexterity and wriggling, and
sprinkling
the oaths with socialism, class hatred, and the last and first day of
creation,
confuses the colonial question with colonization. “The nature of the
dispute over colonial policy must change, on the basis of the
indisputable fact
that the question whether to colonize or not, will soon acquire an
exclusively
historical interest much more with regard to even greater exploitation
of the
colonies, than with regard to settler colonies." The conclusions are
clear:
support the socialist colonial policy, although not named as such. But
here is what is most remarkable: in his article (“Sozalistische
Kolonialpolitik” [Socialist Colonial Policy], “NZ”,
27 -2) Kautsky in response has nothing positive to
say in challenge and, after having used many vivid expressions in order
to
prove the fanciful nature of Vandervelde’s plan “to
help the natives to go the way that one fine day will lead them to
independence”, he at the same time takes the position of Vandervelde
about the need to change the nature of the dispute. Singer, an
intelligent person, perhaps, was not all that wrong.
One way or another, the years described here were the
best period for Kautsky. It is in this short period
of time (after the revolution of 1905) that he expressed his well-known
assessment of our revolution, his ardent statements against militarism,7 his
criticism of socialist colonial policy, his leftist speeches on the general
strike, his decisive position on the taxation policy. About
one of the works he wrote during this period “Sozialismus
und Kolonialpolitik" (1907), Lenin said: 'This pamphlet
was written in the far off times when Kautsky was
still a Marxist”.8 And about
“The Way to Power” (1909), Lenin wrote: “The most complete, the most favourable
for a German Social Democrat (in terms of the hope that it gives) presentation
of views on the tasks of our era”.9
Yes, it is so especially in the sense of the hope it gives. For the greatest contradiction of the “centre” and the deep
foundations of its internal impotence lies in the fact that in the era of the
ultimate development of capitalism, in the era of the utmost deepening of its
antagonistic properties, people who wrote on their banner the violent
destruction of capitalism were oriented in their practice — and then in theory
— to a softening of capitalist contradictions. The “centre” reflected in
itself the inevitable internal contradiction of the mass
working-class movement, since in the era of imperialism, it continues in the
direction that corresponds to the pre-imperialist development of capitalism and
does not go beyond its limits. Sooner or later this
contradiction finds its natural (and the only) resolution — the working-class
movement changes its direction, and is heading toward a revolution. Kautsky, for many reasons, was fit to eradicate centrism
sooner than later. The excellent knowledge of Marx and Engels,
the theoretical hardening in the struggle against revisionism,10 the absence of any connection
with the professional movement that nourished the deepest roots of opportunism,
the comparatively weak party- bureaucratic and party-parliamentary work that
created the psychology of the Social-Democratic leader — all this makes it
understandable, why it was specifically Kautsky who
became the person who “fostered the most propitious hopes from this German
social-democrat”. Alas, he has not justified these hopes. The “official
theorist”11 nullified all the makings and all the prerequisites
of a revolutionary.
But
at that time Kautsky’s fate
had not yet been decided. He wrote: “Nowadays
socialism has become an economic necessity, and the time of its advent
is only
a question of power. To deliver this power to the proletariat is now
more than
ever the most important task of Social- Democracy. There is nothing
more
strange than those socialists who believe that along with this one
should take
care of the further development of the forces of capitalism"
(Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik, p. 37). “The proletariat is now so
strong that it can with great tranquillity expect an impending war.
There
can be no more talk of a premature revolution at a time when the
proletariat
has extracted from the state as much power as it could derive from it,
and when
the state’s reorganization has become a condition for its further rise"
(“The
Way to Power", 1918, p. 73). “Caring friends are afraid that
Social-Democracy through revolution does not come prematurely to state
power.” But, if it is possible for us to prematurely achieve state
power, then this will be the acquisition of the ghost of 'power before
the
revolution,' that is, before the proletariat has won real political
power. So far this has not been possible, so Social Democracy can take
part in the state power, only by selling its political power to the
bourgeois
government. The proletariat, as a class, can never win in this war; at
best,
only the parliamentarians can win who have cut a business type deal"
("The Way
to Power", p. 78).
A lot of such quotes can be cited from Kautsky’s writings of that period. Refer specially
to the article “Positive Arbeit und Revolution ,” [Positive Work and Revolution] "N.
Z.", p. 27-2. What, then, is the theoretical–economic foundation on which this
brilliant revolutionary spirit rested?
The theory of modern capitalism, developed by Kautsky in 1907, is as follows:
1. “Production again and again finds its boundary in
the market. If the capitalist mode of production increased in
the greatest degree the productivity in the production of mass
products, then
at the same time it limits the mass consumption of workers who produce
these
products to a minimum, i.e. produces an increasingly large surplus of
mass-produced goods of personal consumption that must be sold to others
outside the
working class. The place for the sale of this surplus is created, first
of all, by the destruction of primitive rural home industry and
handicrafts
first in their own countries, then in other countries.” But
this kind of market expansion is much slower than the expansion of
production.
From time to time the latter again comes up against obstacles"
(“Sozialismus und. Kolonalpolitik", p. 35).
2. Already in
the 1880s, a rapidly narrowing consumer base led the old capitalist countries to a protracted crisis. This crisis
cannot be resolved by normal capitalist methods, i.e. methods inherent in
healthy, progressive capitalism, that is developing
its productive forces. This proves that the capitalist mode of production has
outlived itself. It seemed that the expansion of the market for personal items
came to its limit. There remained, as it were, one way
out: an increase in the consumption of the working class. The overcoming of the
capitalists, whose immediate interests were opposed to the expansion of
proletarian consumption, and the victory of the working class seemed to be a
persistent economic necessity, the implementation of which must occur in a
short time" (Ibid., p. 36).
3. "Therefore, the capitalists are compelled to
overcome the narrowing of the consumption base by unnatural methods. They found
a number of openings to prolong their dominance, although they all boiled down
to trying to squeeze the productivity of labor on one
hand and, on the other hand, to intensively waste its
products. By this, what the capitalists achieve is that the production moves
forward, at times even at an exceptionally high pace, but at the expense of labour
productivity, which is partly inhibited, is partly wasted
without profit" (p. 36). What are these unnatural methods?
4. Firstly, limiting “external competition through
protectionism, with not only industrial but also agricultural duties being
introduced. But this clearly shows that the task of protectionism is not to
accelerate industrial development, but to ensure super profits to the owners of
the means of production at the expense of consumers, by reducing consumption"
(p. 36).
5. Secondly, restriction of internal competition by
means of entrepreneurial conglomerations. “Not the improvement of technology,
but the improvement of the entrepreneurial organization is now becoming a
decisive factor of profit.” Realisation of super profits by increasing
monopolistic prices, (184) which is all the more feasible, “the less the mass of
manufactured goods, i.e. their supply on the market" (p. 36, 37).
6. Thirdly, militarism. “Mankind has never seen such a
hideous and colossal system of shrinking of the productive forces.” “But the
capitalist mode of production has gone so far that it needs this madness if it
is to continue to exploit the working masses” (p, 37, 99).
7. Fourthly, export of capital. In order to avoid the
need to produce more and more means of consumption for the workers of one’s own
country, capitalism produces increasingly the means of destruction and
production and the means of communication for foreign countries, “i.e. mainly
for economically backward agrarian countries." But,
so that they could buy the goods intended for them, the capitalists of the
exporting country deliver them the necessary money and thereby remain the
owners of all these structures and means. “Capitalists export their products
not as commodities for sale, but as capital for exploitation.” You should not, however, think that this system develops the
productive forces of agrarian countries12.
8. Fifthly, the interests of exporting capital give
rise to the colonial policy. But colonial policy also
represents “a means of prolonging the life of capitalism, not by speeding up
the development of the productive forces, but by delaying them” (p. 44).
Let us examine this theoretical construction.
The first thing that catches your eye is a significant
step forward in comparison with the views of 1901. The clumsy, shapeless
primitive conception of the division of labour between the industrial and
agrarian country as the “basis of the modern mode of production,” gave way to
the theory of realization. In two or three private specific question we come
across formulations that represent not just the development of old views, but a
direct rejection of these old views. So in the old view, if the agrarian duties
were considered the core of the modern customs system, the industrial ones were
considered as an appendage, but now it is just the opposite way: “not only
industrial, but also agricultural duties” are introduced.
But, of course, the most significant part is the attempt
to cover all of the most characteristic features of the modern economy,
proceeding from one single principle — the growing difficulties of realisation.
As early as 1902, Kautsky came to formulate this
principle in "The Theory of Crises." “The demand from the capitalists and the
workers exploited by them is insufficient to absorb the means of consumption
created by a large capitalist industry.
The
latter should look for an additional markets outside of capitalism — in
industries and countries that do not yet have capitalist production” (Russian
edition, 1923, p. 36). But only in 1907 this general
trend of capitalist development was considered in application to the modern
segment of this development and, thus, a detailed theory of modern capitalism
was proposed.
“The
New Industrial System,” for which Kautsky had no theoretical
significance in 1901, in the theory of 1907 is fitted in
neatly. This is achieved by means of the basic
proposition that the tendency of increasing difficulties in
realizations leads
in the 1880s to a situation when realisation becomes impossible under the
old
methods of capitalist management. The “new industrial system” here
appears as
the only method that still remains available to
capitalism if it wants to continue to extort surplus value. Therefore,
capitalist conglomerations, colonial policy, militarism are now
seen by Kautsky as phenomena that can only
disappear together with capitalism. “Overcoming militarism, as well as
the
system of cartels and trusts, is now possible only through socialism”
(38). The
same is true of the colonial policy that according to Kautsky
was a consequence of the export of capital (p. 75 et seq.). With
protectionism,
however, it is not so easy13.
So, the constitutive beginning of the “new industrial
system” is the difficulty of implementation, which has grown and grown into
impossibility of realization. But are not capitalist
conglomerations a simple and direct result of processes of concentration and
centralisation in the capitalist society? There is no doubt that the
difficulties of implementation (in particular long-term depression) speed up
these processes, but would not these processes lead to cartels and trusts
without a continuous increase in implementation difficulties?
And is capitalist expansion (in this case — the export of
capital) not capitalist — and a normal capitalist — method of developing the
world economy? Why should the development of capitalism within the framework of
the old European states be regarded as natural,
progressive, normal, and the emergence of capitalism in Asia, etc., be assessed
as an unnatural clinging of the capitalists to their mode of production, which
has become economically conservative?
And then a direct contradiction, to which the constitutional
principle of Kautsky's theory leads: a constant and
growing surplus of means of consumption is softened (erased) by a system of
strengthened production of means of production. One of the Kautsky formulations was given above, when he expressed
his views on the export of capital. But then we have
before us the old-old theory of “systematic surplus,” which has not even
renewed its vocabulary.
Even further. In Kautsky’s
scheme, all the four signs of modern capitalism that he makes note of — the
capitalist unity, militarism, the export of capital and the colonial policy
generated by the latter — all are theoretically, so to say, equally important.
They all flow in parallel to one another from the extremely narrowed basis of
consumption. They all flow in parallel to one another from the narrowly-restricted basis of consumption. But
is this not just a superficial observation, not thought out synthetically? Are
there not between these four phenomena deeper mutual connections and
dependencies, such that some of them (phenomena) are only
derived from some other? Is an internal connection, and not only
external, between these phenomena through a narrow base of consumption that is
equally remote from them, not a characteristic feature of these phenomena?
There is a striking tension in Kautsky’s
scheme. But, of course, it is superior and richer than
the primitive views of 1901. To a certain extent, it is also
more interesting than the future theory of Rosa Luxemburg, which, however, is
dressed in a completely peculiar form of criticism of Marx’s reproduction
schemes, but in its content represents a step backward because Kautsky tried to explain the full diversity and richness of
modern capitalist reality, while Rosa stayed frozen on the formulation of a law
common to the whole of capitalist history. Her great merit in the
history of political economy, however, of course remains, but it is also a fact
that by proposing the most diverse and profound justification for the theory of
systematic surplus, one that is especially strong precisely because it was
openly directed against Marx, Rosa Luxemburg finally rubbished the sceptical
theory about capitalist development.
We must pay attention to the side of Kautsky’s views, which forms the link between the scheme of
1901 and 1907. The reader has noticed, of course, that Kautsky
exclusively presents all modern economic forms, the whole “new industrial
system” in a negative light. As far as militarism is concerned, this is obvious
and in complete consonance with direct understanding. But
when it comes to the export of capital, Kautsky does
not hesitate to “forget” the elementary truth that the penetration of
capitalism into the natural environment not only ruins the indigenous
population, polarizes it, degenerates natural relations into capitalist ones,
and develops the prerequisites for transformation of a stagnant feudal economy
into the accumulating capitalist economy. Kautsky’s
reasoning astound us by its naivety and helpless indignation... Most
remarkable, however, is the general formulation of the economic content of the
new system. The methods here “all boil down to, on the one hand, to squeeze the
productivity of labour, and on the other, that all the large amounts of
products are thrown to the wind.” But how then is it
possible that “production increases, sometimes even exclusively at a high
pace”? After all, the postscript: “at the expense of the productivity of
labour, which is partly inhibited, partly wasted, is designed to resolve the
contradiction, but only repeats the first formulation, and does not explain how
that production can grow."
With
an absolute denial of
modern capitalism, which even explains the case of an “exceptionally
successful
rate” of production growth by restriction of the social productivity of
labour
(understand it as you like!), which refuses to see that it is the
“modern
industrial system” which is not comparable with anything in the past
that moves
forward productive forces It is a denial which limits itself to a
bookish, and,
in fact, philistine scepticism and completely ignores the real social
processes. Certainly, with such a rejection
of any progressive significance of modern capitalism, revolutionary
conclusions
become obvious. We have, above, looked up a whole page
of revolutionary extracts from various works of Kautsky
in the period under consideration. We can now supplement them with a few
quotations, which are especially aimed at imperialism,
which Kautsky, in fact, at the time (as always)
identified with the desire for colonial conquests. “The imperialist
idea arises
simultaneously with cartels, new protectionism, a
system of militarism and marinism of the new colonial
era, beginning in the 1980s. It is closely connected with all this and is
the
child of the entire economic situation that has increasingly
transformed
capitalism from the means of developing the highest productivity of
labor into a means of delaying this development" (Sozialistische Kolonialpolicy (p. 65).
“But imperialism is unable to provide for
the industry neither the market, nor the suppliers of raw materials. On
the
contrary, it threatens the free interaction of buyers and sellers in
the world
market, but only such intercourses can satisfy the modern industry" (p. 66).
Meanwhile, imperialism is nearing its end. “All of
East Asia, like the whole of the Mohammedan world, has risen for an independent
policy in order to counter any kind of external domination. This brings to a
stop the development of imperialism. It can progress no longer. Meanwhile, it
becomes necessary to develop it further as capitalism keeps developing (“The
Way to Power", p. 71).
For Kautsky of that period,
imperialism, therefore, is inextricably linked with the last stage of
capitalist development, the collapse of imperialism
means the collapse of the whole capitalist system. And
he exclaims with enthusiasm: “Imperialism is the only hope, the only idea
shimmering in the future before the eyes of existing society. Outside of it,
only there is one outcome — socialism. The insanity of 'world politics' will
grow until the proletariat captures the power to direct the foreign policy of
the state, does not overcome the politics of imperialism, replacing it with 'socialism'” (“The Way to Power,” p. 68).
In reviewing Kautsky’s views of 1901, we were convinced that Kautsky, not understanding the contradictory
progressiveness of the “modern industrial system,” sees in it nothing more than
a corrupted capitalism, and believes that Social Democracy can and must fight
the latest perversions of “natural” capitalist development, which are generated
by the “policy of violence” of some powerful capitalist groups. However, on the one
hand, they are contrary to the interests of the rest of the capitalist world
and, on the other hand, an obstacle on the path of direct movement towards
socialism. We saw, in 1905-1909, that Kautsky outgrew this childish babble. But
the main theoretical approach to the phenomena of modern capitalism remained
essentially the same as in 1901: the same corrupted capitalism. The difference
is that now Kautsky sees in this corruption the agony
of capitalism, from which it can no longer be saved. Kautsky does not
want to see that modern capitalism is immeasurably higher than the old capital,
in terms of the ability to rationalize the use of productive forces, in
terms of capacity for quantification and expansion. It acquired this
capacity unprecedented in history due to the fact that new higher forms
of
social production developed within its fold that it adapts to its own
requirements, and to which it must adapt itself, in order to contain in
its
confines the expanding productive forces. The product of this
reciprocal
exchange are ugly, irrational economic forms, the function of which is
to merge
and direct to one goal all the unconnected and mutually exclusive
contents. The irrationality and morbidity of these forms increase as
the productive
forces (intensively and extensively) develop further and as the shell
of
capitalist economy is unable to contain them. To the extent that, in
connection with this, the capitalist system loses the economic ground,
it
attempts to supplement and replace it with a system of violence that
becomes
the economic method and ideology of modern capitalism; in a word, that
the
“modern industrial system” shows itself to be devilishly elastic and
diverse,
having on its side the mighty force of inertia of the economic process
and also
not less mighty human agency made up of the most diverse groups
(including for
some time also some layers of the working class) that all are riveted
by the
capitalist form of production to the chariot of capitalism, being, of
course,
supplied with completely different economic motives. Kautsky does not
even remotely realize this complex
dialectic of the “new industrial system”. He does not even say a word
about the
contradiction between the capitalist form of property and the size of
the productive
forces. Even in an exemplary-developed form (1907-1909), his simplified
mechanical conception touches upon only the surface of the phenomena,
and that
too in a one-sided manner. Where lie the roots of Kautsky’s
weak philosophy of corrupted capitalism that is completely
useless, of course, for the revolutionary proletariat?
Export of capital, modern protectionism, colonial
policy, militarism are all phenomena of the world economy. Essentially, all
these are capitalist methods of resolving the basic economic question of
modernity, the creation and rational organization of an economic territory
encompassing the entire globe. Deepening, expanding and concentrating in the
extreme the production apparatus, pushing the framework of economic ties to the
limits of the world market, and, at the same time, consolidating one separate
national economy into a monopolistic system, and turning a national state into
a direct function of this system, capitalist development brings
mankind close to this issue. Can it be resolved
by capitalist economic methods? This is the central problem around which
revolve all other problems of the contemporary period of history, which in a
long historical period is represented as the epoch in which capitalism and
socialism compete with one another as to which of them will be able to create
and develop a rational world economy. In this greatest
of struggles of all human history, capitalism is doomed. Why? Because if the
world division of labor must be carried out as a task
of capitalist activity by methods of capitalist competition, then a growing and
hopeless antagonism of the process is ensured. Because in
order to realise the objective trend, that has been put on the order of the
day, a world division of labour is required, that is, the equivalence of all
parts of the world economy. However, capitalism promotes the point of interest
of the capital that is being exported, etc., i.e. division into active and
passive members of the world economy, into subjects and objects, or what is
easier to understand — the exploiter and exploited. In practice, this
means the struggle of several “activists”. It is precisely at this point that
the interests of monopoly-organized capitals of different countries collide.
Instead of the planned organization of the world division of labour
we get the forcible incorporation of new areas into one or the other system of
the national division of labor and the struggle that
occurs over such inclusion. Instead of dissolving national economies into a
single world economy, we have the consolidation and isolation of national
economic entities. The war gives rise also to the economic ideology of autarky.
Thus, the tendency to create a world economy inevitably is
turned by capitalism into a tendency to a division of the world economy.
This is the problem of imperialism in real life. Kautsky, who at this time correctly pointed out a number of
reactionary political consequences of imperialism, confined his theoretical
criticism to these, because he was not in a position to reveal the actual
economic contradictions of modern capitalism. Indeed:
1. Protectionism. The
historical task of the old protectionism was the creation of a national
capitalist economy, and the function of modern protectionism is the creation of
world capitalism in the era when the national economy has already been assembled
in a monopolistic system. Hence the defensive character of the first and
offensive character of the second. Hence the possibility of agrarian duties in
the system of cartel protectionism, an opportunity that, given sufficient strength
of the landowner class, turns into reality. Of course, Kautsky
does not see this. For him, old protectionism had an excuse in that it
protected the domestic industry from squeamish foreigners and defended it with
low duties. For the present protectionism, Kautsky
refuses to recognize any objective grounds: in fact it
contributes only to the plunder of the fatherland by a privileged group of
capitalists and delays national consumption. “For industrial countries like
Germany, France, the United States, England, freedom of trade is the least of
evils,” he states in 1901, a view from which he was not free even by 1907.
2. Capital export – the export of capital – is the
tendency of modern business toward a rational distribution of productive
resources on a world scale, as it is realized in the
conditions of the capitalist form of social production. Having as objective
function a reduction in the unevenness in the development of individual
components of the world economy, the export of capital leads to increasing
complexity of this unevenness, to the intensification of the exploitation of
backward nationalities, to their subordination to the interests of exported
capital, to the creation of rentier states. But even
in this completely contradictory form, the objective process nevertheless makes
its way. Of course, Kautsky does not see all this.
All his criticism of the export of capital consists in patriotic condemnation:
after all, he develops foreign countries at the expense of his native
fatherland.
3. Colonial policy. It, according to Kautsky, is only a consequence of the export of capital. We
have shown above how, in order to justify the exclusively destructive role of
colonial policy, Kautsky throws the basics of
Marxism overboard.
4. Capitalist conglomerations, monopolies is the
production system of modern capitalism. It grows as a natural result of the
previous capitalist development, constituting the highest limit of the
concentration and centralisation processes inherent in capitalism. It comprises
(including monopoly banks, which Kautsky completely
ignores) the organizational and regulatory apparatus that capitalism makes use
of for the solution of the problem of the rational world division of labor. The connection between this problem and the economic
apparatus for its solution is thoroughly dialectical. These emerge
simultaneously.
This is nothing but an adequate economic form of the
social production process at that stage of development (extensive and
intensive), when the world economy has itself become a critical problem. On the
other hand, the monopolistic system itself accelerates the execution of world
economic tasks. There is a profound contradiction in the system of monopoly
capitalism. It more or less successfully organizes national capitalism and
imparts a gigantic force by “fusing” it with the apparatus of state power (the
latter Kautsky does not see). It, thus, equips
national capitalism in the struggle for the world economy. But
it is here, at the world arena, where the Sphinx-like riddle of the modern
economy promises death, the monopolistic system, i.e. the only possible
“planned” system of capitalism, finds its limit. Once again
it is confirmed that the methods of capitalist production are an economic
correlate of only that segment of human history that embraces the epoch of
national consolidation of mankind. Within the national economy, capitalism is
able to establish some semblance of a planned production process, albeit at the
expense of an unprecedented increase in oppression over the consumer and with
the inevitable presence of an external sphere of exploitation. But for the world economy, capitalism, even in the era of
the world economic problem, offers only competition and, moreover, one that
constantly turns into its highest form – militarism and wars. The capitalist
mode of production finds its collapse due to the immanent inability to
rationally organize the world’s productive forces precisely at a time when the
rational world economy becomes conditio
sine qua non of economic, and therefore of all, human development. By this
time – and this is the epoch in which we live – capitalist development prepares a
class that, through the experience of destructive and painful disasters and the
“peaceful” methods of capitalism of the last formation, learns to understand
the destiny of the capitalist system and its historical task. It takes upon
himself the difficult task of eliminating the capitalist mode of production and
establishing a new socialized economy that meets the requirements of economic
development.
All this, of course, Kautsky does not see.
Economic criticism here is essentially replaced by
political condemnation, and this latter is based mainly on patriotic arguments:
cartels and trusts restrict national production, squeeze domestic consumption,
and so on.
Look at how Kautsky drags
the working class back to the national trough. In 1901, with such an
argument he wants to prove that the export of capital for the
working class is unprofitable: “The workers do not consider it their
international
duty to reduce their ability to get work and to burden themselves only
so that
their exploiters can also exploit other countries and draw workers from
these
countries into competition with the workers of their own country"
("Trade
Policy," etc., p. 71).
And in 1907, Kautsky, while explaining why the working class must oppose
colonial policy, points out two reasons: “the ethical sense of the proletariat
and the common interests, that unites it with the working people of all the
countries”; what Kautsky understands by this
solidarity, can be seen from the reservation he makes immediately: “in Germany,
its recent colonial policy does not yet allow to truly feel the arrival of
expropriated blacks from Africa to Europe with the aim of lowering earnings
over here” ("Sozialismus und Kolonialpolitik”, p. 62)14.
Is it not a remarkable historical curiosity, when the
mortal enemy of opportunism, Kautsky of 1907,
educates the working class of the advanced countries in the spirit of
national-capitalist superiority and privilege? The revolutionary nature
of Kautsky on questions of imperialism was practically reduced
to the programme for combating the competition of foreign workers, i.e.
simply
to the programme of national limitations. And this was
in his best years, in those years when we were accustomed to regard
Kautsky as an irreproachable revolutionary Marxist. This
happened, in large part, from the fact that the core of Kautsky’s
notions of modern capitalism itself was rotten. It not only did not
comprehend
contemporary capitalism, but ran counter to its
driving forces and tendencies.
III.
Triumph of Sobriety (1910-1914).
I.
The
years 1910-1912 were a turning point in the development of the Social
Democratic centre. During this three-year period, the formation of the centre
ends in its becoming a consistently reformist trend of the working-class
movement, i.e. the tendencies of “real politics” that have long been making
themselves known acquire their final form. By the end of this period, Pannekoek could rightly equate the tactics of the centre
with the revisionist one. But the doubts of sobriety
at the beginning of this period were negligible. The process was
completed quickly and easily, as if a dam had been broken, that was
stopping its development. It unfolded in the form of a struggle against the
leftists and also jointly with the right wing at the
Congresses, in the press and in everyday practice. Three clashes constitute
this struggle —1909-10 with Rosa Luxemburg and Pannekoek,
1911-12, with Radek and Leschpe,
1912 with the whole of the left wing. From the centre, mainly Kautsky
was speaking. In 1909-10 was the year of the issues of strikes by the working class, the role
of parliamentarism, the tactics of deprivation. In 1911-12 the discussion was about the attitude toward
the war, the slogan of disarmament and, in general, of imperialism. In 1912,
the core issues of the revolution and preparations for it were touched upon. In this struggle, a revolutionary course was taking
shape within German Social-Democracy, each time adherence to the
principles in the disputes increased, and by the third stage
we faced a clash of two different ideologies in their main elements. The
character of the dispute had crystallized and become clear. And
if the leftists still argued with caution, arguing for Kautsky
of the past against the present one, and if, on the other hand, the concept of
the left radicals suffered due to its incompleteness, infantile leftism and
contradictions, yet for both parties by the end of the struggle clearly it was
a matter of change in tactics, that the opposition uses the new tactics to
counter the “the old tested tactics, built into the system in its negative
aspect" (Pannekoek).
It is enough to point out two
facts from the party politics of these years so that the content of the process
would become unequivocal: the weakening of the election campaign to the
Reichstag, aimed at setting up a parliamentary bloc with the liberals
(“free-thinkers”) and the faction’s vote for additional taxes, although taxes
were clearly necessitated by increase in armaments. And what about Kautsky? We saw that in 1909 he wrote at his best in the
sense of the hopes raised by this Social Democrat. By 1911, his fate had already been decided. We know, for
example, his classical reformist attitude toward the campaign of a general
strike for the Prussian electoral reform, when he came up with the following
plan: “If it were possible to conduct such work in the Reichstag so that it
would show the masses that the right to vote in the Reichstag is of great
practical value to them, then they would also understand the importance of
electoral reform in the Prussian Landtag ... Only
through the growing importance of the Reichstag in the minds of the masses can the
latter come to understand the meaning of suffrage. On the contrary
the path, proposed by the dreamers about mass actions — to present the
fruitfulness of the Reichstag and by this very fact also the importance of
suffrage right as of little value, is the most erroneous path”15. It is known that, at about this time, in a polemic against Pannekoek, Kautsky wrote: “Never
and under no circumstances can this (i.e., the victory of the proletariat over the
“hostile government”) lead to the destruction of state power, but only to a
well-known shift in the relations of forces within state power ... And the
purpose of our political struggle at the same time, as in the past, is the
achievement of state power through the acquisition of a majority in the
parliament and the transformation of the parliament into a lord over the
government.”16
We know this naive petty- bourgeois sweet idea
of Kautsky about the coming of a “new liberalism”
which he carried around and which he preached in 1911-1912. It
is known, for example, that in 1911 Kautsky wrote in
connection with the question of the attitude of Social-Democracy to the
war:
“Then everyone, even internationalists in conviction, will immediately
become
patriots”, and a year later, polemicizing with Pannekoek,
the centre mouthing the same Kautsky exactly writes
the self-portrait: “In general, if the fatherland is attacked, there
are not
many Social Democrats who would refuse to defend it"... At this time,
Kautsky quickly became the leader of theoretical “semi-officialism” in
German Social-Democracy17. Never
before has theoretical knowledge been directly, from case to case, subordinated
to practical tasks, as Kautsky does in the period
under review. Truly unprecedented cheapening of theory. Opportunism possesses a
magic wand: the one whom it touches, loses the need,
and hence the ability of synthetic thinking, and thus gets hopelessly lost for
Marxism.
This political downslide18,
supported by theoretical sweetening was challenged by the left
radicals,
supported by a broad wave of a revitalized labour movement. Radek in
the following
words gives the diagnosis of the party illness: “The intellectual life
of the
party lagged behind the rate of capitalist development” ... “We need to
eradicate from our consciousness all the vestiges of the old ideology,
which
once had justification in part, but now contradicts reality and leads
only to
delusions “. And Pannekoek gives
a general formulation of the tasks: “The mass actions that have taken
place to
this day constitute only the beginning of a period of revolutionary
class
battles, during which the proletariat must not passively wait until
outside-emerged catastrophes begin to shake the world, must itself
ceaselessly advance,
so that, moving forward in a hard, full of sacrifices to work, to
create his own
strength and his freedom. “This constitutes the 'new tactic' that can
rightfully be called a natural continuation of
the old tactics in its positive aspect.”19
Our tasks can not
include the presentation or criticism of radicalism in the German
Social Democracy.
We dwelt somewhat on the party battles of 1910-1912 to make clearer the
discussion on imperialism that took place at this time between Kautsky,
on the one hand, and Radek-Lensch
on the other, and without which it is impossible to understand the
history of Kautsky’s views to imperialism. In essence, this discussion
summed up the general theoretical basis for disputes over tactics, and
this
contemporariness, even the profound relevance of the discussion on
these
theoretical-economic questions, explains the perseverance and acuteness
of the
struggle on both sides.
The practical core of the dispute was the question of
disarmament, as a socialist slogan against the impending war. But from the very beginning it was clear that this was only
part of the big question of the attitude of Social-Democracy towards
imperialism. And Radek
correctly wrote about the latter: “The main difference in our attitude towards
imperialism consists in our characterisation of its nature. What is
imperialism, what is its relation to capitalist development in general, and to
the expansion of world economy in particular?"20
What
was the position of the left?
A detailed analysis of their theoretical arguments
would reveal many interesting things for the history of the scientific theory
of imperialism. We are here at the sources of the Marxist theory of modern
capitalism, which found its masterful implementation later, in the works of
Lenin. However, this side does not occupy us here. In this connection
it is enough for us to emphasize the conclusions of the “radicals.”
In the book “German
Imperialism and the working class” (1911) Radek
wrote:
And Lensch developed the idea
that capitalism in our time suffocates on its own fat. “The cartel system has
stretched to the limit the revolutionary contradictions between the powerfully
rising productive forces of society and the private-capitalist mode of
production” (“Improvisation”, "N.Z.", 30-2, 365). “Imperialism is the last phase
of capitalist development, which necessarily leads to socialism.” “Imperialism
really means the era of revolution, it is the last word of capitalism” (“Miliz und Abrustung” [Militia and Disarmament], “N.Z.",
32-2, 769-70). “Socialism has ceased to be a distant ideal,
it has become the inevitable goal of practical politics. We have absolutely
nothing to oppose to the capitalist appeal to imperialism, except for the call
for socialism “(Die neuen Wehrvorlagen” [The New Military Templates],
“N.Z.", 30-2, 74).
The same idea was being proved
by Pannekoek:
“Socialism is not a new state that will come somewhere at the end of the path,
when the train has travelled far enough and its strength is exhausted.
Socialism means a completely new, different direction of development, which can
be started at every point of the current development, and which, in fact, will
begin from the day the proletariat conquers power" ("Das Wesen
unserer Gegenwartsforderungen” [The Essence of our Present Demands],
“N.Z.”, 30-2, 814) .
Hence the attitude of the left-radicals to the disarmament
slogan is clear. They remembered Bebel’s phrase at the Jena Party Congress: “The sign of
the times is not disarmament, but armament.” Lensch
pointed out: “We must eliminate rivalry in armament not as a partial
manifestation of imperialism, not as a special disease for which we have a
special medicine in petto — such quackery the party
has always rejected — but in its connection with general imperialist
development" (Miliz und Abrustung”,
“N.Z”, 30-2, 772). And Radek
gave this general formulation: “Social democracy must not see its task in
seeking a curative balm from wounds inflicted by imperialism, but in a
principled struggle against this imperialism, in refusing all its combinations
and in defeating them.”21
Kautsky held views opposite to the whole of this line.
He counterposed the
requirement of a new course to the position that in the tactical “tasks of
Social-Democracy absolutely nothing has changed." He wrote in
the fall of 1911: “The building of organizations, the acquisition of all means
of power, which we are able to seize and retain by our
selves, the study of the state and society and the enlightenment of the
masses: other problems we are still not able to collectively solve and
systematically set for ourselves and for our organizations. The
practical tasks that we can and must set for ourselves do not constitute new
tactics, they represent a continuation of the tactics that for more than four
decades have led the party from one victory to another” ("Die Aktion der Masse, [The Action of the Masses]" "N.Z.", 30-1, 117)
Kautsky did not accept the analysis of the era — “imperialism
or socialism” — given by the left-wing radicals. For him, the philosophy of
the age was expressed in another alternative. “The
question of the suspension and limitation of naval armaments has in fact become
the most persistent question of the decade and posits the option: disarmament
or world war” (Der improvisierte Bruch, N.Z., 30-2,
523). “War or disarmament — that is the problem. Social Democracy is a
determined opponent of war. She wants to prevent it at any cost. Therefore, it
must strive at all costs to have the rivalry in armaments voluntarily
suspended” (Nochmals die Abrustung",”N.Z.”, 30-2, 848).
Kautsky expounded his views on modern capitalism in the most
coherent manner in the article in Neue Zeit of May 1, 1912 ("Der erste
Mai und der Kampf gegen den Militarismus" [May 1 and the Fight against Militarism]). The following thoughts should
be recognized as fundamental in this article:
First thought. It is necessary to distinguish among
the phenomena of capitalism, those that represent a vital necessity for the
capitalist mode of production, from those that, although resting on economic
reasons, do not constitute an economic necessity. An example of the first kind
of phenomena is the appropriation of surplus value or the continuous expansion
of the market. An example of the second type of phenomena according to Kautsky is the desire for an extension of the working day
or the seizure of colonies and spheres of influence, which leads to rivalry in
armament. The second series of phenomena no more than constitute mechanisms to
implement the vital trends of capitalism. But if these
paths are cut off, then capitalist production will find others, and perhaps
even better ones. Therefore, the suppression of the armament system “does not
mean the collapse of capitalism, but only the necessity of using other methods
of capitalist expansion. But all imperialism as a
whole is a phenomenon of the second kind, i.e. although it arose on an economic
basis, it is not an anomic necessity." “Imperialism,” he wrote in another year
in another article (“Nochmals die Abrustung”,
“N.Z.”, 30-2, 51) – is not tantamount to the naturally necessary desire “to
expand, open up new markets and spheres, it is only a special method for
carrying out this aspiration, a method of violence ... Violence does not in any
way constitute an indispensable condition for economic progress.“ The second
thought." Short-sighted greed, the strongest instinct of the capitalists,
generates from their side such actions, which for the sake of a momentary benefit
harm the long-term interests of their own class. Counteracting the exploiting
greed of the capitalists can very often benefit the long-term interests of
bourgeois society.”
These two thoughts constitute the premises of the Kautskyite syllogism about imperialism. It is not difficult
to guess what the conclusion is. “Our agreement of opinion with the bourgeois
defenders of disarmament rests on a commonality of interests in this matter
between the bourgeois world and the proletariat. It is not at
all a sentimental expression, but the sober fact that the bourgeois society as
a whole will just as thoroughly be disrupted by the war as the proletariat,
even more disrupted than the proletariat ... These are very real interests that
are capable of exerting considerable pressure in favour of disarmament through
an international agreement, at least to the more far-sighted sections of the
bourgeoisie or to those sections of it that are particularly affected by
increasing armaments".22
And Kautsky
thus formulates the task of Social-Democracy: “Our immediate task must
be:
supporting and strengthening the petty-bourgeois and bourgeois movement
against
war and armaments” (“N.Z”, 29-2, 101). With the philosophy of this
era, Kautsky’s programme is linked in the following way: As a
result of the agreement of governments, there would be a “situation
that, of
course, would not have ruled out for sure and, once and for all, any
war, but
at least, it would push it back.
And this could lead to the fact that the war between
European great powers would be eliminated forever, since the strength
of the
European proletariat grows with each passing year" (May article 1912,
108).
But the critical point for any theory of imperialism is
that it needs to be checked on facts. Kautsky undertakes
to confirm his theory with a concrete political calculation. And
I must say that the arrogant helplessness, naive sobriety and self-satisfied
uncritical approach of the philistine reaches its peak. Kautsky
wants to prove that there is no basis for a struggle between Britain and
Germany, and in general between European powers. “Africa is
completely subjugated, South Africa is reconciled with England ... At the
moment there is no African problem that would cause a contradiction between the
great powers.23 There is nothing more to think about the division of
China between the great powers ... In general, in Asia, imperialist methods of
forcible conquest are becoming increasingly unsuitable, at least for Western
Europeans, who can only reach Asia by sea. But
all the European powers have an adversary in Russia. It would be effective in
the interests of the international solidarity of the proletariat, as well as
economic development, if Germany, Britain, and France concluded an agreement on
halting increasing armaments and on protecting the integrity of China, Persia
and Turkey against Russian encroachments” (“Nochmals die Abrustung", "N.Z.", 30-2, 851-52).
This was the birth of the future theory of
ultra-imperialism. Even then, Kautsky tried to scientifically substantiate the trend toward
super-imperialism. In an article in May 1912 , we
read: “What has been happening in the relations between capitalist enterprises
for two decades is now beginning to show up in relations between capitalist
states. All of them are striving for expansion, all of them are increasingly
constraining and restricting each other, increasing, thus, the means of war and
multiplying the costs of their expansion to the point that nothing remains of
the profits. As it becomes increasingly clear that the continuation of
competition means destruction of all the participants, the time is approaching
when competition between states will be replaced by
cartel agreements. This is by no means a rejection of expansion of the national
capital, it means only a transition to a cheaper and
safer method."24
On this note we can end the
presentation of the first version of the theory of ultra-imperialism.
His
theoretical unattractiveness saves us from the need to engage in
detailed
criticism. Moresoever, the left-radical writers, in
the struggle against whom this theory was evolved,
noted its mistakes rather well. Radek, polemicizing
with Kautsky, established his main methodological sin
– use of abstractions, as a result of which instead of
living capitalism several abstract categories conjured up that Kautsky
combines in manner useful for him. Radek correctly pointed out that
this scheme is not
sufficient even for the exposition of the general laws of capitalism,
not to
mention the special forms of manifestation of the capitalist mode of
production
in different historical periods. Radek also explained
the connection between Kautsky’s tactical position
and his understanding of imperialism. And Lensch
perfectly expressed this dependence on politics of Kautsky’s
theory, saying that “historically the whole idea has arisen on grounds
of
parliamentarism”.25 But if in the theoretical polemics with the center, the left turned out to be stronger, this does not
mean that they possessed an impeccable theory of imperialism. Their position
was sensitive to real life; and this made their original theoretical and
economic postulates full-blooded even when they were incorrect. The Left
exceeded Kautsky, the more so as they used in their
argumentation the same basic principles on which their bare-boned opponent
once stood. Let us recall that the favourite method in their political polemics
was putting Kautsky’s past views in contrast to his
present ones. This also applies to the theory in which they relied on Kautsky’s old works. Of these, the
leftists uncritically accepted two most important and erroneous propositions:
the grounding of imperialism in the growing difficulties of implementation;26
and — related to it — the notion of imperialism as a policy of expansion of modern
capitalism.27
These profound errors, as it were, strengthened the
revolutionary substance of the left-radical theory, but not more
successfully
than it was with Kautsky’s theory of 1905-1909.
We saw that the revolutionary nature of the latter was an undefended
revolutionism, and, moreover, it
was deprived of defence precisely from a crucial angle; from real life
situation, from the point of view of successes of imperialist
capitalism. To a large extent this applies to the theoretical views of
left- radicals.
The Chemnitz Party Congress, which took place in the
fall of 1912 and discussed the question of imperialism, adopted a
Kautsky resolution based on a Kautskian
report of Haazo, but it was
decorated with revolutionary words. Pannekoek’s
formula: “There is only one way: through imperialism to socialism", met
no
response. A tremendous theoretical task arose before the left movement:
to
substantiate its position more profoundly, more consistently and
broadly, and, first of all, to give a systematic theory of modern
capitalism. That was the problem: the left had a healthy
sense of life, there was a clear picture of the phenomena and
influences of
imperialism, there was a real picture of a whole series of connections
between
the individual manifestations of imperialism, it was the understanding
that a
new system of relations had been created, but their attempts at
comprehending
this system and its main regularities were weak and inconclusive.
Rosa Luxemburg undertook to fill this gap. It was a magnificent attempt,
but not
the one that was needed. Rosa Luxemburg’s book, in
the theoretical mirror, reflected the tremendous impatience of the
growing
revolutionary movement — in all its strengths and weaknesses. Rosa
Luxemburg
failed to break free from the old social-democratic schemes of growing
difficulties of realization, it merely gave this
scheme a logical form of iron determinism, so that it could not bend in
any
direction, exactly as it happened with Kautsky scheme
of 1905-1909.28
But a similar theoretical problem faced the Social
Democrats of the centre. The pre-Congress polemic with the leftists revealed
the theoretical helplessness of the centre. The earlier scheme of Kautsky, developed by him in 1907-1909, with his
revolutionary foresight at its core, was powerless in the face of the
organizational and material successes of imperialist capitalism.29
Of course, Kautsky does not
grieve about this. On the contrary, the inconsistency of the revolutionary
theories concocted by them in the previous years only
strengthens his conviction that the time for all revolutionary practice is
untenable for our time. A new theory of modern capitalism must prove that “the
transition from capitalism to socialism can be accomplished without economic
collapse.”30 Kautsky is trying to adapt
his old scheme on the pragmatic development of industry and agriculture to new
tasks.
Under
the Banner of Marxism No. 11, 1926. pp. 169-201.
Translated from the Russian by Tahir Asghar.
Source:
https:
//drive.google.com/file/d/11BtI4PH6KEDyCLYzUs4U73wqLo01oePD/view?fbclid=IwAR3w3oaX6ZA0kYhZmcdMSTYca5sfS6AF9uADcy1ByXmeN1n7hIAWTtIykBU
Endnotes:
1 However, later — during and especially after
the war — Hilferding’s argument was widely used by
open opportunism.
2
“Alpha and the omega of the newest
protectionist policies are agricultural taxes... i.e. first of all
duties on grain bread, wood, etc." (74). The
same is repeated in the speech at the Stuttgart Party
Congress of 1898: ^“Now the industrial duties are represented only by
correlates of grain”. “Handbuch der Sozial-Demokratische Parteitage von
1863 bis 1909” [Manual of the Social-Democratic Party Congresses from
1863 to 1909], Munich 1910.
3
Example: Russia buys industrial products in
Europe. “The money for this she gets from Belgium, France, Germany, and buys
these products from the industries of these same countries — ships, rails,
cars. The industry of these countries is flourishing, but it has itself paid
for its growth" (p. 58).
4
Thus, the contemporary
colonial policy is judged by Kautsky in the
following manner
(1898: "Aeltere und Neuere Kolonialpolitik" [Old and New Colonial Policy], article in N. Zeit,
16-1, p. 806 and following pages). “On close examination one will find, that the
needs of industrial development did not create the latest phase of colonial policy,
but, on the one hand, it is the needs of those classes, whose interests are in
contradiction with the needs of economic development, and on the other hand,
the needs of the State whose interests contradict the interests of a developed
civilization. In other words, just like the
customs policy, the latest phase of colonial policy is reactionary. For
economic development, it is absolutely irrelevant; on
the contrary, it is even harmful.” See also the article “Militarism and
Socialism in England, written during the Anglo-Boer War (collection “Next
Problems of the International Socialist”, St. Petersburg, 1906, p. 316).
6
Handbuch d. Parteitage, no 5. 238.
7
In 1905, Kautsky
rejected the criterion of a defensive and offensive war for our era; see his
article in “N. Zeit", and in Stuttgart and Essen, he
acted with great fire against this criterion.
8
Note No. 98 to “Imperialism.”
9
“Dead Chauvinism and Living Socialism”, in the
collection “Against the Stream”.
10
True, in this struggle Kautsky,
on a number of significant issues, failed to grasp the fundamental errors of
revisionism. Kautsky often fought a battle on a
non-Marxist platform, accepted Bernstein’s erroneous position on the question,
while fighting against him within the limits of that position. An example of this
is given below, in the final chapter.
11
Expression of Rosa Luxemburg.
12
For a detailed development of this idea, see ibid., pp. 39-41.
14 Here is another example of Kautsky’s
practical opportunism from this period of is theoretical golden period — this
time from colonial politics. In the same book, where he has
set out, full of critical and almost revolutionary imagery, the theory of
modern capitalism, in “Sozialismus and. Kolonialpolitik”, Kautsky’s
practical position on the colonial question is stated in the following words:
“It would be absolutely superfluous if today we ourselves puzzled over the
question of what should be done in each individual colony in order to move its
liberation forward. To seek solutions to this complex problem, which is
different for each colony, would mean doing absolutely unnecessary work, for
the capitalist class will never voluntarily give up any colony”.
“The
mechanisms of the power of the capitalist nations are so incredibly large that
one cannot expect that any of the revolts of the natives could at the present time
achieve their goal. They can only worsen the fate of the natives. No matter how
we raise such uprisings and no matter how we sympathize with the insurgents,
social democracy can not
encourage it" (pp. 75-76). In another place from the same book
we come to know the true meaning of all of Kautsky’s
teachings about the revolutionary tasks of the working class. Concerning the
question of the realization of socialism, Kautsky declares: “On this issue, one can only engage in empty
fantasies without any practical purpose, for our behaviour today cannot be
linked with it” (p. 59). Such, to put it mildly, are some twists in the practice
of the “left” formation.
15
I quote from R.
Luxemburg, "N.Z", 31-2, 836, 37,
16 "Die neue Taktik" [The New Tactic], "N.Z.", 30-2, 726.
17
In 1913, R.
Luxemburg, to whom this expression belongs, wrote about Kautsky’s
theoretical exercises: “This is such an officiousness that
has never been practiced in our party and, certainly, never in the spiritual
and theoretical life of social democracy. In any case, it is
the use of a theory that has nothing to do with the spirit of Marxism.
Being far from the spirit of Marxism, such theoretical knowledge trails behind
practice and which for all that is encouraged and committed by the highest
officials of social-democracy concocts a calming gruel.” ("N.Z." p,
31-?, p. 841 ”Das Offiziosentum
d Theorie" [The Officousness of Theory]).
18
“Our struggle against imperialism”, an article
in “N.Z.", May, for 1 volume “German Revolution", p. 161.
19
"Massenaktion u. Revolution" [Mass Action and Revolution], "N.Z.", 30—2,
21
“Neue Zeit", May 1912, cited from “German Revolution”, p.158.
22
For Kautsky’s
philistine naivety, it is characteristic that in the notorious English proposal
for disarmament he saw proof of his idea of the significance of bourgeois
pacifism. In the article “Nochmals d. Abrustung”. “N.Z." 2, 847, one can read incredible arguments
for a Marxist: "The British and French governments do not believe that rivalry
in armament is a vital condition of capitalism. On the contrary, they are of
the view that with a reduction in armaments they would have achieved much more.
And they are completely right, since England and
France are rapidly approaching the point from which further growth of weapons
is no longer possible.
23
This was written the
day after the war between Italy and Turkey.
24
Kautsky continues:
“Thus, the capitalists of Britain and Germany would not have lost anything if
both states coordinated their foreign policy on this basis to reduce their armaments.
By coming together, these countries, at least could induce the other European
countries to join this deal of theirs and disarm, and the capitalists of these
countries could make inroads with least hindrance into all the countries of the
Eastern Hemisphere much more vigorously". (107-108 ).
25
Radek – "German Revolution",
v. I. Lensch, “N Z.”, 30-2, 771; Lensch
is directly referring to the slogan of disarmament, but in the context of the whole
these words should be related, in general, to imperialism.
26
Lensch wrote: “Capital draws the last regions of the globe that are
not yet subject to it into the vortex of capitalist development. It grabs the
last reservoirs, from which you can still pump out vitality and life
possibilities. But as soon as they are exhausted, the final
hour of capitalism will arrive." “There are growing difficulties stemming from
the contradiction between the productive force of labour that has developed to
the extreme limits and the, more and more, narrowing of the spheres of
realization of surplus capital.” The same is true of Radek
(see, for example, collection Herm. Revolyuts., Vol. I, pp. 170-171).
28 In order to characterize what was required of the left movement in terms of theory, even at that time, the fact must be noted that even the most prominent of Rosa’s political associates did not agree with Rosa’s theory. This applies in particular to Pannekoek, as well as to Radek.
29 That Kautsky’s old theory is incapable of serving as a general theory of the latest stage of capitalism, was felt for a long time. Hilferding’s book (1909) represents an attempt to provide such a theoretical system of modern capitalism that would synthesize the tendency towards organizational improvement and the tendency for the contradictions to deepen — the two main facts of modern capitalist development. Just the fact that the problem was posed makes Hilferding’s study incomparable with the constructions of other theorists of the Second International as far as the richness of content and scientific strength is concerned. On the other hand, the weakness of Hilferding’s theory follows from the prescribed solution of the problem that he correctly grasps. Hilferding cannot imagine the two facts of modern capitalism mentioned in the text, to be different aspects of one fact, the same vector of modern capitalist evolution. Of decisive importance here, of course, is the distorted understanding of the nature and driving mechanisms of the capitalist organizational process. As for the revolutionary conclusions in “Finance Capital” they are politically a product of the era when the Social Democratic centre believed in the power of “extreme" words (the expropriation of the expropriators, the dictatorship of the proletariat, the social revolution, etc.), the truth no longer as practical slogans or practical perspectives, but also as propaganda sayings. Theoretically, Hilferding’s revolutionary conclusions are based on the growth of social and political contradictions of finance capital, but not economic ones, which Hilferding contrasts with social and political, and which, in his views, do not pose insuperable difficulties for the organizational tendencies of modern capitalism. Thus, already in “Finance Capital", under the captivating brilliance and freshness of thought, the scope of the topic, the Marxist dynamics of analysis and revolutionary conclusions, behind the Marxist vocabulary and the literary manner so well known to us, there is a completely non-Marxist and largely metaphysical method of investigation that forces us to recognize the theory of “organized capitalism”, proposed by Hilferding after the war, a logical conclusion of the analysis begun in 1909. However, Hilferding should be studied separately.30 National State, Russian edition, 1917, p. 122.
Click here to return to the October 2019 index.